Houston housing model attracting worldwide attention
"Look to Texas to solve Australian housing supply" by the Unconventional Economist (hat tip to Hugh)Originally, I was just going to include that link among many in another misc items post, but there is so much good material in here, it deserves its own post. Sometimes we forget how good we have it here and exactly why it works so well. It takes an outsider to see and articulate the power of our model, kinda like how it took a Frenchman (Alexis de Tocqueville) to describe America in the 19th century. I highly recommend the whole thing, but here are the Houston-relevant excerpts:
--------------------
Following on from my recent articles on land-use regulations and housing affordability, I want to take readers through Texas’ deregulated and innovative urban planning system, and how this system has assisted in providing Texans with housing that is among the most affordable in the Western world despite very high population growth and easy access to credit....
Finally, because of the low-cost housing in Texas, in addition to the lower rents on offer to businesses (because of lower urban land prices), the cost of living in Texas (as well as Georgia, which operates similar land-use policies) is far lower than the rest of the country. For example, Houston’s overall after-tax living costs are 9% below the nationwide average and 19% below the average for large metro areas (see table).
...
What makes Texas’ housing situation unique is the way in which it:
- Enables a plentiful supply of affordable land for housing and operates speedy housing approval processes; and
- Ensures housing-related infrastucture is adequately financed and provided in order to support the provision of affordable housing.
Houston is an example of a place where, with minimal government regulation, the supply curve for housing is almost perfectly elastic. Houston and surrounding areas have no zoning, so developers face minimal regulation when building on vacant land. Once built, most developers add deed restrictions to their properties in order to enhance their value for buyers who want assurance that the neighborhood will maintain a positive character. But these deed restrictions do not impede further growth, as there is plenty of land in the region without such restrictions.
In the suburbs of Houston, developers often assemble parcels of 5,000 to 10,000 acres, subdivide them into lots for houses, apartments, shops, offices, schools, parks, and other uses, and then sell the lots to builders. The developers provide the roads, water, sewer, and other infrastructure using municipal utility districts, which allow homebuyers to repay their share of the costs over 30 years. At any given moment, hundreds of thousands of home sites might be available, allowing builders to quickly respond to changing demand by building both on speculation and for custom buyers…
Houston developers allow homebuyers to pay off infrastructure costs over 30 years, impact fees or development charges require up-front payments often totaling tens of thousands of dollars. The difference is crucial for housing affordability: since development charges increase the cost of new housing, sellers of existing homes can get a windfall by raising the price of their houses by an amount equal to those charges, thus reducing the general level of housing affordability.
Increasing land and housing costs make other things more expensive as well. When housing is more expensive, for example, businesses must pay their employees more so that workers can afford to live in the region…
If lower interest rates increase demand for housing, Houston-area homebuilders respond by building more homes; [by contrast, in supply-restricted cities like the] San Francisco-area, builders respond by filing more applications, which may wait several years for approval. If government purchase of a large block of land for a park or open space restricts supply, Houston-area builders can simply go somewhere else nearby; in the San Francisco area, the nearest alternative building location is more than 50 miles away.
Notice that inelastic supply not only makes housing prices rapidly increase with small increases in demand; it also makes housing prices rapidly fall with small decreases in demand. This is exacerbated by lengthy permitting periods that can put homebuilders out of phase with the market. Thus, land-use restrictions create conditions ripe for housing bubbles.As mentioned in the above extract, a key feature of the Texan housing system is the Municipal Utility District (MUD) financing system for housing-related infrastructure and services. Here’s a break-down of how the MUD system works:
- Utilities are installed and maintained by the companies (electricity, telephone etc) since they receive the revenue.
- The developer has to install the roads.
- Large subdivisions are allocated areas for parks and schools.
- The developer installs the sewerage and water and gets it back from the Municipal Utility District.
- MUD is a special-purpose district that provides public utilities (such as electricity, natural gas, sewage treatment, water, and waste collection/management) to the residents of that district.
- MUDs are formed by a vote of the area, and represented by board of directors who are voted on by the local people.
- The MUD borrows money via the bond market to pay for building (via the developer) and operating (via the MUD) these services. The MUD bonds are then repaid via taxes on the home owners of around 1% of the home values per year.
- Schools are also built and funded via bonds and repaid via the same taxes on the homeowner.
In the first phase of the U.S. housing market boom and bust, many large cities (primarily on the East and West coasts) saw a prolonged run-up in prices. Demand for housing, driven by low interest rates and a growing economy, combined with supply restrictions—such as zoning laws, high permitting costs and “not in my backyard” regulations—to contribute to rapid price appreciation…These price increases then fed off themselves. Rising prices—whether for gold, corn or houses—often foster a bubble mentality, contributing to speculative demand…
Atlanta [Georgia], Dallas and Houston [Texas]…weathered increased demand largely with new construction rather than price appreciation because of the ease of building new homes. While some are dismissive of this developer-friendly attitude that allows such rapid construction, the approach clearly carries significant benefits for the homebuyer…
The Houston Example:
Houston saw tremendous job and population growth over the last decade, ranking it high among the 12 largest U.S. metropolitan areas in both metrics…
Given that Houstonians had access to the same new types of mortgages as the rest of the country and that Houston has had greater population growth than other large metros, we might expect price appreciation to be stronger in Houston than elsewhere. However, the opposite has been true.
Houston’s large supply of land means that demand growth primarily results in more construction, not higher prices. Construction levels are limited by the availability of two kinds of developable land: the previously undeveloped, generally found on a metro’s outskirts, and the redeveloping, usually in a city’s interior. In both cases, Houston’s policies are relatively permissive, making the metro friendly toward development.
The most fundamental difference between Houston and other cities lies in how they provide (or in Houston’s case, do not provide) water, sewer and drainage to developments on the urban fringe. In Houston, developers can create a municipal utility district, or MUD, to provide these services on their properties and can finance these with tax-free bonds. Houston requires developers to build MUDs in such a way that they eventually could be connected to the city’s corresponding infrastructure, but they begin as self-sufficient enterprises.
In other cities, developments must be connected to the city’s water and sewer lines, confining new projects to nearby or adjacent land since the cost of building lengthy lines is prohibitive. In metro Houston, by contrast, virtually any large parcel of land can become a new suburb, especially given the metro’s expansive highway system…
Much of the land in metro Houston is not assigned a specific use. So much land is available in Houston that the cost of each incremental unit rises slowly and keeps the average cost below that of more restrictive metros. Even in the face of significant population growth, this large supply keeps land prices in Houston stable, which over time contributes to lower home prices…
Indeed, Houston and other metros such as Dallas and Atlanta that have relatively more permissive development policies have lower housing prices than more restrictive places do.So let’s sum-up Texas’ housing achievements:
- high quality housing that is less than half the cost of equivalent Australian homes;
- price stability – since Texan homes never bubbled then busted, unlike the supply-restricted US states;
- low levels of household debt – due to the low cost of Texan housing; and
- macroeconomic stability – resulting from Texas’ price stability and low debt levels.
...From where I am sitting, the Texan model of urban planning seems far superior to the dysfunctional, prescriptive mess currently presiding across Australia. Having the opportunity to purchase a new family home for $150,000 would be a dream come true for many Australians, many of whom are instead required to load-up on debt to buy smaller homes at twice the cost.
The question you, the reader, needs to ask yourself is why aren’t Australia’s policy makers undertaking study tours to learn from their counterparts in Texas, instead of throwing endless sums of taxpayer dollars into demand-side measures – like the first home buyers grants and negative gearing tax concessions – which throw the demand-supply balance further out of kilter and makes homes even less affordable?
4 Comments:
Atlanta isn't the ideal example to use given its huge job loses this past decade. It was by far the largest affordable metro area with a housing market that tanked during the recession.
Texans should be very proud of themselves in having sensible policies that maintained housing at affordable levels through this past decade.
The big lesson here is - do not repeat the mistakes of others.
Hugh Pavletich
www.PerformanceUrbanPlanning.org
Christchurch
New Zealand
"price stability – since Texan homes never bubbled then busted, unlike the supply-restricted US states;"
In my experience we did have a bubble, but it was a supply bubble as opposed to a price bubble.
I started grad school in 2007 and me and my dad bought a house together for me to live in and rent out the extra rooms. Both of us were a little worried about buying. He was worried because he got burned by buying our family home during the oil boom. I was worried because all of the economists were saying that we had a housing bubble. I thought Houston would be okay because we didn't have the price increases.
I bought in a new development in Oct. 2007 for 95,000. By spring of 09 about a third of the houses in my neighborhood were for sale, either foreclosures or short sales. The copies of my house were going for between 40-70,000. Now the going rate for my house is ~80-85,000.
The real story of the bubble in Houston is how the market corrects itself without govt. intervention in the presence of continued growth.
In my neighborhood the foreclosed properties turned out to be primarily owned by out of state speculators, who had every incentive to just mail in the keys when they got underwater. Owner occupiers on the other hand never got underwater enough for mailing in the keys to be worthwhile.
After the speculators jumped ship we saw prices bottom out and the developer stopped building houses. After about a year that excess supply had been bought up and with the growth of the Houston area the Demand for housing started to catch back up to the supply so we saw the prices start to inch back up. Eventually the prices came back to a high enough level that the developer started building houses again. Now we are at a point where the house I bought (which was the smallest floor plan and was supposed to be last they were going to build) for 95,000 is now being built and sold for 85,000.
So yes from my experience we did appear to have a bubble. Our experience was different because it was primarily excess supply instead of excess prices. The large presence of speculator's without non-economic attachment or any chance of govt. assistance allowed the market to correct itself quickly. And, finally the pace of growth in the Houston area allowed us to quickly grow out of the bust.
I got the dates a little wrong. I bought the house in oct 06.
Post a Comment
<< Home